Recently I have read the following book. Its main points in chapters one to three are as follows:
Book Title: Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: the Growth of Industrial Policy,
1925-1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Main points:
Ch.
1-
by common agreement among the Japanese, the ‘miracle’ first appeared to them
during 1962 and scholars began to search for the cause of the miracle. (p. 3)
Between 1946 and 1976, the Japanese economy increased 55-fold. (p. 5)
-according to Johnson so far, Western scholars tried
to see what the American could learn from Japan, instead of analysis what had
caused this. One explanation of the miracle belonged to the socioeconomic school,
i.e. anything but politics, for example national characters, the
‘unique-structural-feature’, or ‘the free-ride’ analysis etc. (p. 8)
-the goal of the book was to lay out some of the
main Japanese institutions in economic field. (p. 8)
- as John Roberts had put it, Japan’s ‘miraculous’
emergence as a first-rate economic power in the 1960s had been described exhaustively
by Japanese and foreign writers and yet little of these literature provided credible
explanation of how it was done, or by whom. This study was an attempt to answer
these questions. (p.11)
-the school which the author places himself was the
school that stressed the role of the developmental state in the economic
miracle. (p.17) The question was: to look at how the government intervened and
for what purposed. In countries that were late to industrialization, the state
led the industrialization drive, which took on developmental function. In terms
of government-business relationship, the US was regulatory orientation, whereas
Japan was mainly developmental orientated. (p.19)
-another way to distinguish the policy of a state
was to see its priority in economic policy. In a plan-rational state, the
government concerned the structure of domestic industry. For a market-rational
state it would not have an industrial policy, it would stress rules and
reciprocal concession. (p.20) Japan was a developmental, plan-rational state
whose economic orientation was the key to industrial policy. (p.20) From about
1955, for Japan the goals had been high-speed growth. (p.20)
-within the developmental state, the center that
exerted the greatest positive influence was the one that created and executed
industrial policy. MITI’s dominance in this area had been characterized as the
‘pilot agency’. But its true power was its control of industrial policy. (p.26)
-a measurement of what MITI had achieved was a shift
in ‘industrial structure’. In the first half of 1950s, about 30 percent of the export
still consisted of fibers and textiles; only 14 percent was in the category of
machines. The composition changed in the first half of the 1960s. Fibers and
textile went down to 8 while machinery was 39 percent. (p.31) Johnson argues
that this shift was the operative mechanism of the economic miracle. He asserts
that Japanese government exercised a much greater degree of both in
intervention and protection that other western European countries, and thus made
the difference that led to the miracle. (p.31) Thus Johnson had a prima facie
case for MITI’s role in the economic miracle.
-Johnson argues the time frame of 1925-75 was need
for two reasons for his research. First MITI only realized very late that what
they were doing had added up to an implicit theory of developmental stage; they
had no theory or model of industrial policy in the 1960s, not until the
creation of the Industrial Source Council in 1964. Second, there was a direct
continuity between prewar and postwar official in MITI. MITI was the
reincarnation of the wartime MCI and the MM. MITI. Modern Japanese industrial policy
was linked to the reign of Emperor Hirohito. (p.33)
-Ch. 2-
talks about the economic bureaucracy. The author was concerned to explain why the
discrepancy between the formal authorities of either the Emperor (prewar) or
the Diet (postwar) and the actual powers held by the state bureaucrat, and why
this discrepancy contributed to the success of the developmental state. (p.35)
- Japan had long displayed a marked separation in
its political system between reigning and ruling. (p.35)
- the origins of separation between power and
authority could be found in Japan’s feudal past and in the emergence of the
developmental state during the Meiji era. (p.36) Prewar bureaucrats were not
“civil servants”, but rather “official of emperor” appointed by him and
answerable only to him. (p.38)
- the success of the economic bureaucracy in
preserving more or less intact its pre-existing influence was the perquisite to
the success of the industrial policies of the 1950s. It did not simply preserve
its influence, it expanded: its size increased, and that the political parties
were too weak to exercise political power. (pp.44-5)
- quoting Kusayanagi Daizo, the book shows that all
human relations in Japanese society were based on four key of ‘factions’: 1. the
family and matrimonial cliques, 2. the clansmen or person from the same
locality, 3. the same university graduates, and 4.the faction based on money.
All these occurred in the bureaucracy, the first two was minor, and the last
two was important. (p.55)
- a serious issue in Japan was not the occasional
abuse of office by higher officials but a pattern of cooperation between the
government and big business that might have unintended consequence. (p. 68)
- the re-employment of retired government
bureaucrats (amakudari)
on the board of industries designated as economically strategic also created
many opportunities for hand-in-glove relationships. (p. 69)
-one reason for private sectors to accept amakudari was the extensive licensing
and approving authority of the government. Companies believed that having
former bureaucrats (amakudari) among
their executives could facilitate obtaining licenses. (p.70)
- MITI had several characteristic that distinguished
it from other economic bureaucracy. It was the smallest among the economic
ministries in terms of personnel. MITI exercised control over money through its
ability to approve credit or authorized expenditures done by the Japan
Development Bank, the Electric power Development Company etc. The ministry
supervised the spending of some Yen 160.9 billion. (p.79)
- Japanese analysts unusually characterized the
basic outlook of MITI officials as ‘nationalistic’. (p.80) After the war MITI
had always been hostile to American-style price completion and anti-trust legislation.
(p.81)
Ch.3-
talks
about the history of the accomplishment of MITI. According to Johnson, the
first phase of modern Japanese industry policy seemed related to the postwar
economic miracle, but it was in fact directly relevant for several reasons: it
faced same problems in these two different periods of 1920s and 1950s. That was
the need to restore competitive ability in international trade.
-Japan did not experience a radical discontinuity in
its civilian bureaucratic and economic elites since the 1920s. Many top leaders
in the government were active in the organization and execution of industrial
policy before, during, and after the war. (p.114)
-the theme of historical continuity also suggested
the fact that industrial policy was rooted in Japan’s political rationality and
conscious institutional innovation, not in Japanese culture, vestiges of
feudalism, or any other special characteristics of Japanese society. (p.114)
- economic crisis gave birth to industrial policy. The
long recession in 1918 led to the creation of MCI and the first attempt at
industrial policy. Similarly the deflation panic of 1949 led to the creation of
MITI and the renewal of industrial policy. (p.114) The suitably modified
production version of the 1950s amazed the world by its performance. From this
perspective the early years of industrial policy were a period of gestation and
perfection in the Japanese institution and industrial policy. (p.115)
(to be continued)
沒有留言:
張貼留言